During my undergraduate
days, I took an introductory course in economics. The course was taught by a tandem
of economists and, as well, brought in a variety of guest speakers ...
including Paul Samuelson.
I didn’t do very well in
the course ... I got some sort of a C. In fact, I was flunking the course prior
to making the sort of recovery in the second semester that was sufficient to
bring my overall average up to a passing grade.
One possible
interpretation of the foregoing difficulties was that I was just too dumb to
understand economics. Another possibility is that economics was just too dumb
to be understood.
My instructors might have
been inclined toward the former explanation. In retrospect, I am inclined
toward the latter possibility.
The first half of the
course focused on microeconomics, while the second semester explored the world
of macroeconomics. For the most part, no facet of microeconomics made very much
sense to me -- and the realm of macroeconomics was not far behind in that
regard.
For instance, consider
the idea of a market. In fact, let’s consider one of the most basic forms of
market there is – namely, the labor market.
Labor markets are all
about the manner in which companies (employers) negotiate with potential workers – and vice
versa – in order to arrive at a compensation agreement through which various
forms of labor will be offered in exchange for certain kinds of payment. I was
told that the ‘invisible hand’ of the market would move the foregoing
negotiation to some sort of equilibrium point in which there would be a
sufficient number of workers who would be prepared to accept a given level of compensation
to permit the company to move forward with production.
There were comparable
markets involving such things as resource pricing and product/service
consumption. In all of these markets, the invisible hand of the market would
push the negotiation dynamic toward an equilibrium point in which buyers and
sellers would cross paths in a mutually agreeable manner.
Some said that the best
kind of markets were free ones. Markets which, for whatever reason, were not
free, introduced various kinds of distortion into the process of negotiating
among buyers and sellers that would affect the efficiency of those markets in
problematic ways.
Efficient markets were
desirable because they minimized costs and maximized productivity. Moreover,
since free markets were believed to be efficient, then free markets also were
desirable.
When markets were left to
themselves, the invisible hand of the marketplace supposedly would solve
whatever economic problems arose within those systems. Consequently, free
markets had the potential to be self-regulating.
Okay, let’s return to the
idea of a labor market. If one permits workers and companies to freely
negotiate with one another – that is, without interference – in relation to
determining the price of labor, what might happen?
Much will depend on the
supply and demand of labor. If there are a lot of people seeking work -- yet
there are only a limited number of jobs -- then it is a buyers’ market from the
standpoint of management and, therefore, companies likely will try to force a
fairly low point of equilibrium -- when the situation is graphed out -- in
which there will be a sufficient number of people that are desperate enough for
work who, as a result, will be prepared to accept a relatively low compensation
package offer from the company.
On the other hand, if
there are not many workers available, or not many workers with the right sorts
of skills who are present, then, it is a sellers’ market as far as labor is
concerned. Therefore, labor will be in a much better position to push the
equilibrium point in an upward direction as far as the size of the compensation
package is concerned.
There really isn’t any
invisible hand at work in the market process. Needs of one kind in a given
market tend to pair up with needs of another kind in that same market and,
thereby, establish relationships that are -- to one degree or another –
considered to be reciprocal or compatible in nature.
What makes the hand of
the market appear invisible is that all of the forces at work in individuals
(e.g., motivation, interests, needs, character, and values) take place in a
largely hidden form of psychological calculus that manifests itself in choices
of one kind or another. When those choices are collectively tabulated, one can
plot the character of the dynamics at work in a given market.
However, there is nothing
mysterious or mystical taking place. People who are hungry, or who have
children who are hungry, or who have bills to pay, can be induced to work in
exchange for a compensation package that will keep those individuals
impoverished or at a subsistence level of survival since the alternative – not
working -- seems even more disastrous.
From the perspective of
capital, those markets are most efficient which are able to generate a high
degree of productivity as inexpensively as possible. From the perspective of
capital, labor is merely a cost, and, therefore, what happens to the lives that
are represented by that kind of a cost is irrelevant to the interests of
capital.
From the perspective of human
beings, those markets are most efficient which are able to satisfy the
collective need for justice, tranquility, defense, welfare, and liberty at a
cost that everyone is prepared to accept. If capital is used in a manner that
will not assist individuals to realize the aforementioned collective need, then
capital is being used inefficiently.
In most forms of
capitalism, efficiency is a function of what enhances or obstructs the flow of,
and return on, capital. However, why should capital, rather than the essential
needs of human beings, be used to set the standard for what constitutes
efficiency?
The above way of
approaching things seems exceedingly arbitrary. Why isn’t a human-friendly
standard of efficiency used to induce markets to become self-regulating?
A company that is able to
negotiate a low wage for workers while demanding a high return of productivity
from those same individuals might be quite efficient. However, if one considers
the problems that are likely to ensue from the foregoing sort of miserly
compensation package – e.g., poverty, crime, dysfunctional families, health
issues, worker safety, quality of education, emotional disturbance, substance
abuse, and community conflict – then, companies that have adopted the standard
which defines efficiency purely in terms of capital flow and return on capital
have externalized the true costs of producing whatever they produce and,
consequently, from the perspective of the community or the overall ecology of
society, are not all that efficient.
There seem to be at least
two schools of accounting principles at work in the foregoing considerations.
One accounting method concerns itself only with the flow of capital through a
company and the profits which are generated by that flow, while the other modality
of accounting keeps tract of the multiplicity of costs which accrue to the
community and arise as a result of the characteristics of that capital flow
through the company in question.
What is efficient from
the perspective of a company is not necessarily efficient from the perspective
of the surrounding community. Yet, the former perspective is the standard which
tends to be adopted by those who operate out of capitalistic framework when it
comes to issues of efficiency, and this never made any sense to me.
Furthermore, negotiations
which are entered into out of desperation – such as often, but not always, occurs with labor -- do not really have much of the aura of freedom about them.
The idea of ‘free markets’ exploits the positive feelings that surround the
term “free” and uses those feelings to camouflage the fact that the only facets
of those markets that are actually free are capital and those who possess that
commodity.
From the point of view of
capital, governmental regulations constitute sources of distortion which are
being introduced into markets ... distortions that will adversely affect the
efficiency of that market because those regulations tend to adversely affect
the flow of capital and/or lower the rate of return on capital investment On
the other hand, material, financial, emotional, social, and environmental
pressures acting on a given party – for example, labor – during market
negotiations also constitute potential sources of distortion that are being
introduced into such a market that, from the perspective of human beings, will
adversely affect how truly “free” those markets are, as well as whether, or
not, the idea of “efficiency” will
be defined in a manner that serves the interests of ‘We the People’ or only the
interests of capital.
Being able to induce
workers to accept a certain level of compensation is one thing. Being able to
arrange for a fair level of compensation with respect to those workers is often
quite another matter.
Why are only markets that
meet the criteria of capital efficiency considered to be free? Why is ‘freedom’
being defined as a function of what happens to the flow of capital within a
market. Moreover, if allegedly free markets are not fair, then, what value do those
markets have except to serve the interests of capital against the interests of
‘We the People’?
How does the invisible
hand of the market solve the problem of ‘fairness?’ If people are forced by
circumstances to accept a low-level package of compensation for their labor,
then as long as efficiency and freedom are defined by the needs of capital,
those laborers will never be treated with fairness.
Moreover, how does the
invisible hand of the market solve the problems of: justice, tranquility,
common defense, general welfare, and liberty? There is no room for any of the
foregoing issues within the flow charts of capital interests because those
issues tend to complicate the flow of capital with respect to the generation of
maximized profits.
What is truly remarkable
is the manner in which the language of capitalistic economics has been used to
induce people to cede their moral and intellectual agency to a theory of life
that is largely devoid of humanity. Free market enterprise is not about what is
good for humanity but about what is good for capital formation, capital
accumulation, and the capacity of capital to control the lives of people to
serve the interests of capital.
The language of: “free”
markets, efficiency, and the invisible hand of the marketplace are at the heart
of capitalist economics. However, those terms only make sense – in a
pathological sort of way -- when one deals with an abstracted notion of capital
flows from which issues of: justice, tranquility, common defense, general
welfare, and liberty for the collective – as opposed to the capitalist – have
been removed, and it never made any sense to me why anyone would want to learn
about an economic theory which was so biased in its depiction of the world and
so readily inclined to slip into destructive behavior of one kind or another
with respect to the ramifications of capitalism for those who lived outside the
channel-ways of capital flow.
Two other economic terms
that are skewed by the biases of those who wish to control commercial activity
and, thereby, undermine basic sovereignty among ‘We the People’ are: “wealth”
and “capital.” The “commerce clause” in Section 8 of Article I of the
Philadelphia Constitution indicates that Congress shall have the power to
regulate commerce “with foreign nations, and among the several states, and with
the Indian tribes,” but that clause does not give Congress the power to
regulate such commerce in order to favor either corporations or capitalism (as
a theoretical system of philosophy).
The ‘commerce clause’ is
supposed to serve the principles and purposes of the Preamble. After all,
allegedly, the Preamble is the reason why the Philadelphia Constitution was
established.
There is nothing in that
Preamble about corporations or capitalism. It is entirely about ‘We the People’
and the establishing of: a more perfect union, justice, tranquility, common
defense, general welfare, and liberty for the people.
Therefore, with respect
to the regulation of commerce, wealth is a function of whether, or not, the
purposes and principles of the constitutional Preamble are realized. Real
wealth – not the superficial, shallow wealth of financial self-aggrandizement
-- gives expression to the degree to which the people of the United States
collectively enjoy the benefits of justice, tranquility, defense, welfare, and
liberty.
Wealth is not a matter of
financial accumulation. Wealth is about the quality of life among ‘We the
People’ considered both individually and collectively.
Unfortunately, there
tends to be an inverse correlation between the level of financial wealth of the
few and the quality of life of ‘We the People.’ In other words, regulating
commerce in a way that enables a relatively few people to become wealthy in a
financial sense tends to adversely affect the quality of life for the
generality of people, and, as a result, this sort of an arrangement does not
serve the purposes and principles for which the Philadelphia Constitution was
supposedly created ... which, in turn, means that the foregoing manner of
regulating commerce is neither ‘necessary’ nor ‘proper’ per the requirements of
the Philadelphia Constitution.
In short, defining
“wealth” in purely financial and material terms cannot be reconciled with the
Preamble to the Philadelphia Constitution. Justice, tranquility, defense,
welfare, and liberty transcend those purely financial and material
considerations ... although, to be sure, financial and material dynamics have a
role to play to help realize the purposes and principles that are entailed by
the Preamble.
Similarly, the proper
meaning of ‘capitalism’ should be about the flow and enhancement of the capital
of human life in conjunction with a fiduciary responsibility to the environment
that makes that kind of flow and enhancement possible (i.e., it is the ground
out of which all forms of capital emerge). One degrades the idea of capitalism
when one reduces it down to merely financial/material considerations ... in
fact, if capitalism does not serve the interests of the collectivity of human
beings, then, it is no better than socialism and communism – both of which seek
to use arbitrary philosophies to undermine the basic sovereignty of human
beings.
Therefore, the manner in
which my introductory course in economics tended to approach and engage the
ideas of ‘wealth’ and ‘capital’ made no sense to me. I was being asked to
accept a perspective that went contrary to my feelings and thinking with
respect to democracy, morality, humanity, life, and justice.
Another part of the
lexicon of capitalist economics is ‘competition.’ Supposedly, markets are at best
when they are competitive.
When companies compete
for a share of the market, then, they must do whatever they can to attract
customers. Competitive markets are said to enhance efficiency by driving down
costs, improving productivity, and enhancing the quality of products.
However, competition also
can bring out the worst in people. When this occurs, then people will cheat,
lie, manipulate, exploit, bribe, and abuse others – whether workers, suppliers,
customers, or society -- in whatever way they can get away with in order to
generate a profit.
Many economists are
inclined to argue that in the long run, illicit forms of competition – that is,
forms that involve unethical behavior – will not be rewarded and, therefore,
the only stable form of competition is fair competition. The foregoing
perspective assumes, of course, that, sooner or later, the unethical behavior being
alluded to will be uncovered – in the courts, by the media, through political
activity -- but this is not always the case ... especially if the courts, the
media, and political activity happen to be co-operating, in one fashion or
another, to cover up or camouflage that sort of unethical behavior.
After all, government
officials have been known to accept bribes or campaign contributions in
exchange for looking the other way with respect to problematic economic
activity. Similarly, media outlets have been known to kill or alter stories
that cast an unattractive light on one, or another, of their advertisers.
Moreover, those judges whose understanding of the world is, for whatever
reasons, heavily influenced by capitalistic biases (for example the judge in
the Dodge v. Ford case), will
interpret the law in ways that are favorable to corporations and other capital
interests rather than ‘We the People.’
Unethical commercial
activity is best uncovered when a given market is transparent and
well-regulated. Those who conduct themselves in an unethical manner are adept
at obfuscating matters as well as undermining regulation ... which is why one
hears so many ideological psychopathic entrepreneurs criticizing the presence
of regulation in their markets since regulation – when it is done properly –
interferes with the desire of those individuals to have their unethical
practices remain in the dark and out of sight of inquiring minds.
According to Adam Smith,
a market that is made up of a number of relatively small, and roughly equal,
competitors is likely to produce the fairest form of competition. Problems
arise, however, when the participants in a given market are either limited
and/or not necessarily equal to one another, and, under those conditions,
‘competitors’ are capable of leveraging the asymmetry of power distribution of these
sorts of circumstances to hold a market hostage. One possibility that arises
from the foregoing sort of asymmetry is that companies in such a position of
power will not necessarily seek to enhance the quality of products, or increase
productivity, or decrease the prices of products/services.
The emergence of
monopolies, trusts, mergers, and multinational corporations over the last one
hundred and seventy years has come to have a dominant – and, for the generality
of people, problematic -- impact on almost all markets. Consequently,
competition has become increasingly less fair as it is shaped by the interests,
resources, powers, influences, and financial clout of a variety of commercial
behemoths in conjunction with their fellow political, media, and judicial
supporters.
Markets that are
dominated by a few companies are not free. The efficiency of those markets is
distorted by the manner in which the very meaning of “efficiency” must –
according to the controlling companies -- be defined by the interests of those
companies and by the manner in which whatever negotiations that occur in those
markets are driven by the advantages enjoyed by those companies relative to other players in that market.
This is most readily
understood in the context of labor markets where companies use their financial
and political power to prevent workers from receiving fair compensation for the
labor of the latter individuals. From the perspective of management, efficient
companies are those which have poorly compensated workers generating high rates
of productivity that lead to attractive profit margins.
Consequently, companies
that compete with one another – whether fairly or illicitly -- will not
necessarily help to bring about the realization of basic sovereignty for the
generality of people. Sovereignty requires co-operation, not competition.
Sovereignty is not a
zero-sum game. Sovereignty is rooted in the willingness of people to
co-operatively struggle against and resist all forces – including commercial
ones – that would seek to undermine individual and collective attempts to
activate the principles inherent in the basic right of sovereignty.
Furthermore, I am not
aware of any proof that shows, beyond a reasonable doubt, that co-operation is
incapable of generating (if not improving upon) what competition supposedly
does – that is, lower prices, enhance quality of products/services, and generate higher
productivity. In fact, co-operative commercial activity is much more likely to
lead to the realization of sovereignty – both individually and collectively
(and this resonates to some degree with what Henry Ford was trying to
accomplish before the Dodge brothers took him to court) – than is the sort of
competition which is narrowly focused on inducing capital flow to generate
profits.
The division of labor
with which Adam Smith was so enthralled in The
Wealth of Nations is about co-operation, not competition. By breaking a job
down into small steps that are performed by different people, one can produce
more – for example, pins -- than one could achieve if one were to have
different people compete with one another when each of them was responsible for
the entire production process of individual pins.
Studies tend to indicate
that companies work best when their employees co-operate with one another. On
the other hand, a variety of research also tends to show that companies become
dysfunctional when their employees are engaged in competitive, internecine turf
wars with one another.
In sports, teams that
work co-operatively with one another tend to do better than those teams in
which its members are in competition with one another. In addition, plays,
movies, and television programs tend to be better when all the participants in
those productions are working from the same page.
Furthermore, military
success depends on all facets of the military being able to harmonize their
efforts with one another. While competition, within limits, may help soldiers
to hone some of their skills, the goal is to generate a set of people who are
capable of co-operating with one another in order to be able to meet their
assigned objective.
If co-operation – rather
than competition – works best in the division of labor, corporate functioning,
team success, and military operations, then why not entertain the possibility
that co-operation among companies for the purposes of establishing an economy
that meshed with issues of individual and collective sovereignty might be a
much better way of engaging the problems of life than to suppose that
competition will be able to resolve all problems? In other words, another basic
term – that is, ‘competition’ – which is drawn from the lexicon of the sort of
capitalistic economics to which I was introduced as a fledgling student doesn’t
necessarily make all that much sense.
Capital and labor should
not have an antagonistic relationship with one another. In fact, capital and
labor are two sides of the same coin of sovereignty.
Capital is a catalyst for
labor. Labor is a catalyst for capital.
Their relationship – if
functioning properly -- is symbiotic in nature. When financial capital
(capitalism), labor (communism), or the state (socialism) seeks to assume
control of that relationship, sovereignty is adversely affected.
Commercial activity is a
necessary part of society. However -- when, at the expense of basic sovereignty
(the only right which can be demonstrated beyond a reasonable doubt to reflect
the actual existential status of human beings) commercial activity is filtered
through the biases of arbitrary philosophies – such as capitalism, socialism,
and communism – commercial activity becomes destructive of purposes and
principles that are essential to being human.
-----
Back in the mid-1960s, a
few friends of mine somehow – and quite mistakenly -- got the idea that I was
something of a financial wizard. If any of them had taken the time to critically
reflect on the quality of my living arrangements or the kind of job that I had,
they might have come to a more appropriate conclusion.
Nevertheless, one day a
friend showed up unannounced at my apartment in East Cambridge and indicated
that another friend of mine had told him that he should come to me for
assistance with respect to helping him find a way to earn some quick money in
the stock market. Perhaps, they were confused about how I got into Harvard ...
which wasn’t through possessing an impressive stock portfolio or travelling in
elite financial circles.
I was kind of dumbfounded
when the aforementioned individual showed up on my doorstep with his plea for
help. However, not wanting to turn the person away without attempting to offer
some form of assistance, I managed to blurt out a few things about ‘put
options’ which I had come across somewhere in a newspaper, magazine, or book
and alluded to the possibility that one could sometimes purchase stocks on
margin ... the stock market’s version of placing a bet (making a trade) with a
bookie (broker) and putting it on one’s tab (account).
I explained – in a rather
halting and unsure manner – that if the value of the stock rose, one could sell
the stock at a profit without having risked any of one’s own money. In other
words one would have leveraged the money ‘borrowed’ from the brokerage firm and
translated the loan into a financial gain.
Of course, if the value
of the stock went down and the stock broker called for the margin to be paid,
then the outcome became more problematic. Under those circumstances, one would
have incurred a debt which had to be paid ... and if the size of the loss was
more than one’s available cash flow, one had a problem.
I tried to tell my friend
that I really didn’t know much, if anything, about such things. Unfortunately,
and to paraphrase someone else, even the relatively ignorant are treated like
wise men in the land of the completely ignorant.
After listening to me for
a short while, my friend thanked me and left. Hopefully, he was smart enough
not to invest much stock in my ramblings.
I’ve never had the
‘green’ thumb -- or inclination -- necessary to nurture the growth of money. On
the other hand, I was fairly accomplished at inducing my debt load to assume a
weed-like growth pattern.
Notwithstanding all my
financial incompetence, however, I do tend to grasp some basic truths
concerning the stock market. For instance, with the possible exception of an
IPO, or initial public offering, in which people are actually investing money
in a company with the hope that both the company and the investor will get a
good return on their respective investments, the stock market is, for the most
part, really nothing more than a legalized form of gambling.
Most people buy and sell
stocks to make money, and, as a result, they often don’t actually care about
the company (or its people) whose stock is purchased, any more than a gambler
cares about the individuals on the sports team that he bets for or against. The
way one makes money in the stock market is to buy stocks that rise in value
and, then, to sell those stocks off before they lose their enhanced value.
A stock rises in value
because of the perception – whether correct or not – that the company for which
the stock serves as something of a public persona is undergoing certain kinds
of commercial dynamics that, for whatever reason, will lead to a more
advantageous positioning within a given market that, in turn, might enable the
company to make profits in the future. Similarly a stock goes down in value if
the perception – whether correct or not – concerning a company’s future
economic outlook becomes stormy or risky.
There are all kinds of
indicators which people (both professional and amateur) look at in order to try
to develop a sense, financially speaking, of where a given company might be
headed -- and when. The quality of competition, technological developments
(present or forthcoming), labor contracts, possible transitions in management
personnel or strategies, rumors of one kind or another, credit ratings, debt
burden, forthcoming mergers or possible hostile take-overs, and so on, are all
fuel for the process of trying to analyze which way a given investment fire
will burn, or for how long, and with what level of intensity.
Oftentimes, the value of
a company tends to rise if the productivity of that company is perceived to
increase. Productivity is enhanced when costs go down while the quantity and/or
quality of output either stays the same or improves.
There are several ways in
which costs might be lowered. For example, when a company: Decreases the
compensation package for workers (involving wage/salary levels, health
benefits, and/or retirement plans); or, asks the workers to do more for the
same level of compensation; or, downsizes and, as a result, lays workers off;
or, moves its operations to another state or country where labor will work for
less, and/or the taxes, environmental standards, and safety considerations are
less regulated, if at all, then productivity is likely to be measured as having
increased.
The more money that is
made by those who play the stock market, then, quite frequently, the more the
quality of life is lowered for those people – i.e., the workers -- who help
subsidize those profits through: Lower wages, lost jobs, increased work
burdens, slashed pensions, and/or diminished safety considerations). In those
sorts of cases, stock profits are made by leveraging the labor of workers, and,
in many – but not all -- ways, picking stock winners is about identifying those
companies where there is a high likelihood that the life of workers will, in
some way, be diminished in order to give such a company an alleged competitive
advantage in the marketplace so that the value of the stock will rise and
someone will make a profit when the stock is sold or when a dividend is issued.
Hedge funds, mutual
funds, venture capital, brokerage firms, and banks give expression to
systematic attempts to develop betting or trading strategies concerning the
perceived value, over time, of various companies, commodities, currencies,
services, governments, and resources. Those bets or trades often leverage the
lives of human beings associated with those companies, commodities, currencies,
governments, or resources and, if necessary, place the lives of those human
beings at risk for purposes of turning a profit.
Generally speaking, the
riskier a given trade is, the greater is the possible payout associated with
that trade. The other side of this coin is that the higher the risk, then the
greater is the likelihood that one will lose the money invested ... bets are
placed and the wheel is spun ... round and round she goes.
Time, interest rates,
price, yield, market conditions, inflation, and other factors are gathered
together in various formulas designed to determine the risk associated with any
given betting or trading strategy. Those formulas might be linear or non-linear
in character, but they tend to be based on, and attempt to reflectively model,
what has happened within a given market across a certain time frame, and, then,
such calculations are used to make forecasts with respect to various possible
kinds of economic and financial trends into the future.
The more nuanced and
complex a given formula or model is, the more vulnerable that formula or model
is to fluctuations in the real world that fall outside the predicted parameters
of such a trading formula or model ... and, quite frequently, those
fluctuations don’t have to be very big in order for trouble to creep into one’s
financial life. For instance, the property or house that is associated with a
mortgage that has been leveraged at 20 to 1 only has to fall in value by a
little more than 5 % before the whole investment is lost.
Mathematicians,
physicists, and engineers are often hired by companies to handle the
complexities of model construction. When those constructions work, the currents
of flowing money are propitious, but when those model/formulae don’t succeed,
money still flows, but the currents transform into a riptide that tears a
person’s life apart and pulls her or him under.
The foregoing formulas
and models are based on the assumption that the future will look much like what
has happened during the period which is being modeled. Unfortunately, the
future doesn’t always repeat the recent past, and when this occurs, financial
losses become very likely.
As was the case with
respect to the ‘counsel’ which I gave to my friend back in 1965, if one can
manage to make money with other people’s money – called leveraging – then, when
this works out, this is the best sort of scenario. However, when this kind of
arrangement doesn’t work out, then trouble ensues ... margins are called, and
one’s life slides into a financial abyss.
When one juxtaposes
complex mathematical formulae and models – ones whose relationship with reality
is understood, if at all, by very, very few people, including the people who
invent them – next to risk-taking behavior, uncertainty, leveraged money, and
ideological psychopathy, one is asking for trouble. Welcome to the world of
derivatives.
In simplest terms,
derivatives are a function of – or derived from -- the value of some underlying
asset (e.g., mortgages). Trading or betting strategies (in the form of complex
mathematical models and formulae) concerning those derivatives – which are
financial instruments rotating about the performance of some given asset --
attempt to forecast or track how the value of the underlying asset will unfold
over time and generate – hopefully – some sort of return on investment concerning
that asset.
Mortgage-backed
securities – with mortgages being the underlying asset, and the securities
being the derivative, or financial instrument, based on that asset – are only
one of many kinds of derivatives that were developed over the years. Whatever
names are assigned to those financial instruments, nevertheless, when one
removes all the hype, complexity, mystery, and opacity surrounding the idea of
derivatives, those financial instruments are nothing more than a form of gambling
involving whether, or not, some underlying asset will prove to be a winner or a
loser.
Simple derivatives begat
more complex forms of derivatives. For instance, out of mortgage-backed
securities arose what are called collateralized debt obligations or CDOs.
In CDOs, the underlying
assets were often pooled together – mixing financially strong manifestations of
the asset with less financially sound editions of the same asset. For example,
mortgages based upon sound lending principles might be thrown together with mortgages
that were based on manipulation, misinformation, disinformation, and something
other than sound lending practices (e.g., the realm of subprime mortgages)
These pooled assets were,
then, run through a tranching blender (in the form of some kind of mathematical
formula or set of formulae) to create different streams of risk/payout
investment possibilities. The foregoing sorts of arrangements were often given
credit ratings as a guide to the degree of risk associated with the likelihood
of realizing any given stream of income, much as certain people in Las Vegas
create betting lines with respect to this or that sporting event.
Unfortunately, quite a
few people who set the credit-rating part of the betting line in relation to an
array of derivatives did so in a dishonest fashion. As a result, derivatives
were often knowingly rated with a higher – and, therefore, less risky – credit
rating than those derivatives deserved, and, in the process, investors were
scammed.
CDOs didn’t necessarily
include just one category of assets. A variety of assets with a range of values
might be included in the aforementioned tranching packages, and, consequently,
each CDO had its own unique risk/payout investment structure.
As long as the underlying
assets performed well – or were made to appear to be successful -- then
everyone (investors, model makers, financial instrument innovators, banks,
hedge funds, brokers, and financiers of various descriptions) earned money.
When those underlying assets performed poorly -- or not at all -- then
financial fault lines began to run in all directions.
Because the early returns
from playing the derivative’s version of roulette appeared to be fairly
lucrative, many people began to jump onto the financial bandwagon and place
their bets. Quite a few of them did this with leveraged money -- that is, money
borrowed from other people which was, then, used to purchase one, or another,
brand of the financial instruments known as derivatives – and among the
borrowers were investment houses, banks, hedge funds, pension funds, and so on.
A variety of companies
were so highly leveraged in the derivatives gambling games that when the market
began to go south (partly – but only partly -- set in motion when people in the
subprime mortgage market could not pay their mortgages when interest rates rose
and/or jobs were lost) panic beset the gaming tables. As a result, margin calls
began to be issued like falling dominos with respect to various loans that had
been leveraged to purchase derivatives because many of the loaning institutions
and organizations were, themselves, scrambling to pay off their own failed
leveraged betting strategies for which margin calls had been issued.
The monster of
derivatives was spliced to the monster of leveraged money by unsuspecting or
indifferent financial ‘scientists,’ and a chimerical form of being was created
that began to consume the world. A weapons-grade financial plague had been
released.
In December of 2007,
derivatives trading, of one kind or another, accounted for nearly $700 trillion
dollars. This amount of money is more than 10 times the GWP – Gross World
Product – of all the nations on the face of the Earth.
Obviously, if this great
gaming table of derivatives – with its many risky bets -- begins to unravel,
there are not enough assets in existence to cover the money which has been
wagered. Individuals and a variety of financial institutions will fall ... but
so will many countries.
One of the problems –
and, there, are many others -- surrounding the idea of derivatives is that they
were not regulated in any way. In essence, they constituted the promised land
of capitalist economics – namely, a completely free market in which capital –
through the magic of the invisible hand of the market – would be enabled to travel
in any direction without interference.
The results were
disastrous. Free market economics didn’t work, and if one has any doubts about
this go and ask: Bear Sterns, Fannie Mae, Fanny Mac, Lehman Brothers, Merrill
Lynch, American International Group, and a host of other champions of ‘free
market capitalism’.
A fundamental precept of
capitalism was dysfunctional because the idea of free markets is an economic
fiction, just as corporations are a legal fiction. Those sorts of fiction work
great in the fantasyland of theoreticians, but they are difficult to reconcile
with the real-world needs of human beings.
Markets form, or are
generated, in accordance with not only the strengths of the players in those
markets, but, as well such markets are formed in accordance with the biases,
ignorance, and character flaws of those same players. The so-called invisible
hand of the market is nothing else but the dynamics of those strengths and
weaknesses made manifest.
There can be no guarantee
that the biases, ignorance, and character flaws that help shape a given market
will automatically generate equilibrium points within that space which will
magically give expression to solutions capable of satisfying the needs of
everyone associated with that space. As computer programmers have been known to
say: garbage in, garbage out.
Greed, ambition,
selfishness, arrogance, hubris, ruthlessness, ignorance, dishonesty,
irresponsibility, callousness, aggressiveness, recklessness, impulsiveness,
abusiveness, remorselessness, emotional shallowness, cruelty, duplicity,
egocentrism, as well as lack of empathy for, or indifference to the pain of,
others – that is, most, if not all, of the characteristics of ideological
psychopathy – were fully present during the organizing, shaping, orienting, and
coloring of the derivatives market. Unfortunately, most economists and
politicians were too blinded by their delusional, ideological thinking about
the nature of reality to be able to understand that from the very beginning,
the so-called free market of derivatives was nothing but a figment of someone’s
imagination that, among other things, failed to take into account the manner in
which ideological psychopaths will seek to exploit such an opportunity without
any regard for the possible destructive ramifications that are likely to ensue
for either themselves and/or others.
Derivatives, along with
other financial instruments, are not – as some advocates try to argue – a means
of introducing: Increased choices; enhanced credit; and improved pricing into
the world for the benefit of investors. The foregoing points are merely part of
the marketing ploy that is being used to induce people to believe that the
creation of the derivatives roulette wheel – along with other manner of
financial gaming tables -- is just another form of ‘free markets’ in action, or
that everything associated with derivatives is being done for the benefit of
‘We the People’ when, in truth, at best, only a few people – with the help of
government assistance -- are able to surf the wave of financial tides to a safe
and satisfying conclusion ... sooner or later, most people wipe out.
Like the Walt Disney
version of the Sorcerer’s Apprentice, the dynamics of derivatives (i.e., the
water-carrying-ever-multiplying brooms) have taken on a life of their own. The
complexity of: The tranching process, the leveraging process, and the
destructive unraveling process that arises from failed betting/trading
strategies is so extensive, that the full extent of the damage is still not
known, and – to mix metaphors -- like the fault lines of an earthquake zone,
the fractured world of derivative is very likely awaiting the right set of
political and economic conditions to once again shake apart the lives of human
beings, along with their associated institutions of governance and economics.
Within the context of the
foregoing betting/trading strategies, capital in the form of money is given
preference to capital in the form of human beings. When capital is defined in
terms of financial considerations, human beings have a value only to the extent
that those individuals are capable of facilitating and enhancing the flow of
money.
When capital is a
function of financial considerations, it tends to be a purely quantitative
transaction. When capital is a function of human considerations that involve
basic sovereignty, capital assumes a variety of qualitative features that, in
many ways, cannot be adequately represented through the quantitative metrics of
dollars, euros, yuan, pesos, or the value of a derivative.
Many people want the
dynamics of free market economics to govern the world. However, the meaning of
“free” in those dynamics tends to be a function of ideological biases – such as
those which are present in the derivatives market -- that are antithetical to
the actual sovereignty of human beings and which wish (intentionally or
unintentionally) to place the lives of human beings under the control of the
movements of financial capital ... movements that, all too frequently, are
‘freely’ manipulated by the machinations of various corporations, as well
as by different representatives of
the executive, legislative, judicial and state branches of government.
Those who are the primary
shapers of financial markets of whatever description – that is, banks, corporations,
insurance companies, hedge funds, investment houses, multinationals, and the
government – have given ‘We the People’ no reason to trust them to do the right
thing when it comes to helping to establish, protect, or enhance the
sovereignty of individuals, considered both singly and collectively. Economics
has failed every bit as spectacularly as has governance when it comes to
nurturing, protecting, and honoring the basic sovereignty of ‘We the People.’
Attempting to impose on
people the biased ideology of capitalism (its bias gives preference to the
movement of capital considered as a financial commodity) is no different than
seeking to impose the biased ideologies of socialism (the bias is in favor of
centralized or state public policy planning) or communism (the bias is in favor
of a limited, materialistic conception of classless owners of the means of
production) on people. Sovereignty is not about ideology, but, rather,
sovereignty is about recognizing the nature of the human condition and having a
fair opportunity to push back the horizons of ignorance ... and neither
capitalism, socialism, nor communism is capable of establishing that kind of
fairness or even proving in any non-arbitrary way what that ‘fairness’ might
entail.
-----
The idea of ‘rational
utility maximization’ – or, alternatively, ‘maximizing a rational utility
function’ -- plays a central role in economic theory. The actors in economic
dramas are assumed to be individuals playing the role of rational agents who
are interested in maximizing their potential according to some sort of theory
of utility.
On the surface, the
foregoing assumptions seem ‘reasonable.’ However, with a little reflection,
that which appears to be ‘reasonable’ tends to become less so.
For example, what are the
criteria of ‘rationality’? Moreover, what justifies using those criteria?
Is it necessarily
rational to pursue that which is pleasurable? Is it necessarily rational to
avoid that which is painful?
Accomplishment often
comes through difficulty. Enduring through, and triumphing over, difficulty
frequently establishes its own metric of pleasure.
On the other hand,
pleasurable experiences sometimes entail problematic consequences. For
instance, the highs of various kinds of addiction are capable of motivating one
to seek more of the same until that kind of addictive behavior establishes its
own metric of pain.
Obviously, the
significance of pleasure and pain depends on the ultimate nature of reality.
Furthermore, one interprets, or measures, the character of pleasure and pain
against the possible meanings of life.
People have different
ideas about what they consider to be desirable forms of pleasure and pain.
Motivational patterns are woven into life as a function of such ideas, or,
alternatively, those patters arise out of the phenomenology of experience as we
come to identify the kind of circumstances which are deemed to be worthwhile to
seek out, as well as those situations that are considered to be worthy of being
avoided.
Not all motivational
patters are necessarily rational. Yet, this does not prevent people from acting
in accordance with those patterns.
Consequently, not all
utility functions are necessarily rational. This raises the problem of having
to differentiate between rational and irrational utility functions.
Furthermore, utility
functions come in qualitative, quantitative, and mixed varieties. Not all
qualitative utility functions (e.g., liberty, justice, truth, tranquility, and
spirituality) can be solved through one, or another, kind of pricing
arrangement or accurately reflected through quantitative measurements.
Sometimes we have
understandings that are backed up by a variety of evidence indicating that a
certain path forward is a ‘rational’ one. Unfortunately, our behaviors don’t
always reflect those understandings ... that is, we don’t always act in
accordance with what we ‘know’ -- or believe we know.
To use reason and logic
to seek or acquire that which is not in one’s best interests, does not
necessarily constitute rational behavior. To use reason and logic to avoid
doing that which might be in one’s best interests, also does not necessarily
constitute rational behavior.
Human beings are not
always purely rational beings. Emotion and reason interact with one another in
complex ways.
Sometimes reason informs
emotion (for example, helping to modulate anger, jealousy, greed, and so on),
and benefits ensue from that arrangement. Sometimes emotion (in the form of
empathy, compassion, love, gratitude, and the like) informs reason and benefits
often follow from that dynamic.
Is reason without the
right sort of emotional counsel necessarily rational? How does one determine
what ‘the right sort of emotional counsel’ is?
If reason is divorced
from considerations of justice and morality, is that sort of reason rational?
If not, then in what way must justice and/or morality be understood in order
for reason to qualify as being rational?
Can one maximize justice
for oneself without also maximizing justice for others? What is the
relationship between morality and rationality?
The idea of rational
utility maximization was, and continues to be, at the heart of the array of
formulae and models that populate the derivatives market. However, a great deal
went wrong with the “rational,” “utility,” and “maximization” parts of those
formulae and models.
The idea of rational
utility maximization is at the heart of most markets. Yet, many of those
markets often fail because the nature of the understanding of different
participants in those markets concerning the nature of ‘rationality,’
‘utility,’ and ‘maximization’ has destructive ramifications for not only the
market but the surrounding society as well.
For instance, socializing
costs and privatizing profits – as often is done in the case of free market economics
-- might give expression to a form of ‘rational utility maximization’ for one,
or another, company. However, that kind of a utility function is parasitic and,
sooner or later, the host will die, and, therefore, so will the parasite.
When different rational
utility functions vie with one another in the marketplace, there is more than
one possible outcome for such a dynamic. Not all outcomes of the foregoing sort
of interaction will necessarily be favorable to either the participants or to
society.
The invisible hand of the
market is not inherently benign. It reflects, and gives expression, to the
intentions and character of the participants in that market.
The Iroquois – and
several other Indian nations – have indicated that every judgment and decision
made by the people of that nation must take into consideration the impact of
that decision/judgment on the next seven generations of people. How many
economic decisions are made with the foregoing sort of understanding in mind?
If the answer is not very
many – and I believe this answer overestimates the situation – then, just how
rational are the utility functions that are employed in those economic models
for purposes of maximizing outcomes? Moreover, for whom are those functions
being maximized, and at what cost to others or the environment, and with what
justification?
Economists – and most of
the rest of us -- are ignorant about (that is, we cannot prove, beyond a
reasonable doubt, the truth concerning) the nature of: intelligence,
consciousness, reason, rationality, emotion, motivation, justice, morality, or
life. Consequently, how can they – or we -- make any constructive suggestions
concerning the idea of maximizing rational utility functions when everything
that is said in this respect tends to be entirely arbitrary?
Rational agents are
assumed by economists to be individuals who have perfect knowledge of all
relevant considerations concerning a given market. Even if one were to concede that
kind of an assumption – which seems a dumb thing to do -- nevertheless, having
knowledge of a situation and understanding what do with such knowledge -- and
when or to what extent or in relation to whom -- are not necessarily
coextensive.
The gulf between
information and knowledge is considerable. So, too, is the gulf between
knowledge and wisdom.
Economists have a lot of
data or information. They have very little knowledge or wisdom which can be
demonstrated to be accurately reflective of reality in a manner that is beyond
all reasonable doubt, and if economics can’t satisfy that sort of a standard,
then, why should anyone comply with economics’ interpretation of what
constitutes ‘rational utility maximization’, let alone its understanding – or
lack thereof – concerning the nature and purpose of life?
Misinformation,
disinformation, rumors, dishonesty, limited information, incorrect
understanding, and uncertainty characterize all markets. Idealized venues in
which those sorts of problematic features are not present have very little to
do with the real world.
What does it mean to talk
about maximizing rational utility functions when we are immersed in an ocean of
unknowing and uncertainty? Is it rational to make decisions with incomplete
information?
Are interpretations of
incomplete information necessarily rational? Are attempts to maximize some form
of utility function in the light of that kind of incomplete information
necessarily rational?
What if our
interpretations and attempts to maximize those utility functions turn out to be
wrong ... as was the case with derivatives? Is it rational to try to maximize
one’s own utility function if this will have adverse consequences for others?
The nature of life
requires us all to make choices. The capacity to choose does not guarantee that
those decisions will be rational, maximizing, or serve some utility function.
The idea of maximizing
rational utility is an economic fiction which has more to do with mythology
than reality. It is a snipe hunt that all too many economists and politicians
wish to impose on people as a proposed solution to the problem of sovereignty.
In reality – and the
derivatives fiasco is very instructive in this regard – the ‘science’ of snipe
hunting that is being advanced by many free market economists is a process that
tends to entangle sovereignty – both individual and collective – in endless
forms of arbitrary exercises that, sooner or later, lead to oppression and
injustice. Such snipe hunts are
inherently unstable because they do not accurately reflect the existential and
epistemological circumstances in which we find ourselves, and, consequently,
one should not be surprised to discover that the history of capitalism is
replete with the foregoing sorts of instabilities.
Ideological psychopaths
all possess rational utility functions which they are attempting to maximize.
Their utility function gives expression to various, characteristic features of
their ideological orientation.
Ideological psychopaths
consider their utility functions to be rational ‘because’ they (both the
individuals and the functions) are inflexibly tied to the definitions,
assumptions, logic, and values of their delusional system of thinking and,
therefore, those individuals have no way to independently and objectively
verify the degree of truth, if any, in their perspective. Because there is a
method to their pathology, they confuse and conflate methodology with
rationality.
Making sense of things is
not necessarily the same as establishing the truth of those things. Having a
system of logic and reasoning does not render a system rational, any more than
the logic and reasoning of a paranoid schizophrenic are rendered rational just
because the logic and reasoning inherent in their condition seem compelling to
the individual operating under the influences of that sort of pathology.
Free market capitalist
theorists are ideological psychopaths for a number of reasons. For instance,
not only is their understanding of reality delusional – that is, it is a false
belief system -- but, as well, they have a pathological expectation that everyone
else should be willing to comply with, if not subsidize, that sort of a
delusional worldview.
The foregoing
expectations are pathological because they tend to lead to a variety of very
problematic behaviors and inclinations. As is the case with those who are born
with psychopathic tendencies, ideological psychopaths who are immersed in the
delusional system of ‘free market capitalistic theory’ often exhibit qualities
of: arrogance, impulsivity, recklessness, irresponsibility, abusiveness, manipulation,
dishonesty, emotional shallowness, cruelty, callousness, self-aggrandizement,
selfishness, and egocentricity, as well as a lack of empathy concerning other
human beings, together with a lack of remorse or sense of conscience in
relation to the manner in which their own satisfaction must be paid for through
the pain and suffering of other human beings.
Like many natural-born
psychopaths, ideological psychopaths of the free market capitalistic variety
use their language skills to manage and manipulate the impressions of others.
Advertising and public relations activities give expression to that kind of a
skill-set because the intention of advertising and public relations is to frame
people’s attention by excluding all the problematic ramifications from the
picture (e.g., in relation to: worker compensation, hazardous working
conditions, environmental pollution, tax evasion, customer safety, undue
influence on the media and politicians) which often arise in parallel with the
profits that are to be made in relation to the alleged value of some given
product or service (i.e., the focus of advertising).
Advertising, marketing,
and public relations are used to induce potential customers or the public to
cede their moral and intellectual agency to the company and product being
promoted. Like natural-born psychopaths, ideological psychopaths of the free
market capitalistic system use the allure of sex, self-image, power, and
control -- or one’s insecurities concerning those issues -- in an attempt to
push and prod our buttons of existential vulnerability.
-----
To the best of my
knowledge, I have never met John Perkins ... although, conceivably, my degree
of separation from him might have been much less than I suppose. More
specifically, during my undergraduate days, I had to work various jobs in order
to try to survive while going to school, and one of those jobs began around
1965-1966 at the Business and Economics Library at Boston University.
John Perkins began
college in 1965 at Boston University. His major was business, and, therefore,
he was enrolled in the Business Administration program at BU.
Since I often ran the
‘desk’ for signing out books, periodicals, and course materials that had been
placed on reserve at the Business and Economics Library, there is a fair chance
that, at some point, I might have checked out books, periodicals, or reserve
materials for him. Otherwise, we probably just passed one another like two
silent, darkened ships in the night along the hallways and in the elevators of
the Boston University School of Business and Economics.
The Business library
often served as a social meeting place for students who were occupying the
interstitial times and spaces between classes. Therefore, the library tended to
be a rowdy place, and, once or twice, in my best sarcastic form, I had to
venture into the rather large reading room and make an announcement that there
had been complaints from many of the students that the people who were using
the library for purposes of studying were interfering with the attempts of the
complainants to converse with one another.
I don’t know to which of
the two foregoing group John Perkins belonged. Of course, I am assuming that he
was actually in the library during such instances.
There is another piece of
information about the Business and Economics Library that might serve as a sort
of segue into the ideas of John Perkins. From time to time, the staff would
check the library’s actual holdings against the card catalogue to determine
what books, if any, were missing.
Ironically, the section
of books in the library that tended to suffer the worst losses – including
defacing – dealt with one, or another, aspect of business ethics. The relevance
of the foregoing fact to the experience of John Perkins is that he -- according
to his own later confessions -- became engaged in a very ethically-challenged
form of work for many years.
Although, initially, Mr.
Perkins had been interested in joining the Special Forces and going to
Southeast Asia to help fight the Vietnam War, he turned against the war when
the media began to report on the many atrocities which were being committed
there. Later on he learned Spanish, and following completion of his studies at
Boston University, Mr. Perkins joined the Peace Corps, and went to Ecuador.
While in Ecuador, he met
a man who was employed by MAIN (Chas T. Main, Incorporated). MAIN was a
consulting firm whose primary task was to determine the ‘suitability’ of
various countries for being granted loans from the World Bank for purposes of
building hydroelectric dams, roads, and other similar projects designed to
enhance a country’s infrastructure.
The man encouraged John
Perkins to apply for work at MAIN after he finished his Peace Corps assignment.
In the meantime, he asked John to write to him with respect to whatever was
going on in Ecuador.
As a result, Mr. Perkins
wrote 15, or so, relatively long responses concerning events in Ecuador. Later
on, he was hired by MAIN.
He became an econometric
analyst. His job was to generate economic forecasts concerning different
countries that would serve as the basis for deciding whether, or not, MAIN
should become involved in various engineering projects in those areas.
His first assignment was
Java in Indonesia. He was informed that Java’s economy was about to explode,
and his forthcoming economic forecast should reflect that ‘fact.’
He learned how to use
statistics to construct whatever economic models that might be needed to serve
the interests of MAIN or those for whom MAIN served as a consultant. In other
words, part of his task was to develop economic reports and models for a
country that would seem to justify making loans to that country ... policy
positions that already had been determined prior to the generation of those
reports or the construction of relevant models.
Consequently, the purpose
of the foregoing reports and models was to ‘rationalize’ loaning money to
certain countries so that the loans could, in turn, be paid to a variety of
corporations (e.g., Haliburton, Bechtel, and others) to undertake massive
infrastructure projects in those nations. The reports and models were part of
an ingenious make-work scheme for western corporations in which countries – via
MAIN – were induced to sign off on loans for hundreds of millions of dollars
that, then, would be forwarded to different companies for services rendered for
those countries ... irrespective of whether those services were actually
capable of benefitting the people of the country that was going into debt in
order to generate profits for western companies.
John Perkins’ job at MAIN
had a second dimension to it. Once the aforementioned loans had been made to a
given country, he was tasked with arranging things so that the debt could not
be repaid and, instead, the country would be induced to go even deeper into
debt.
When the amount of a
country’s debt reached a certain level, that nation would be pressured into
slashing spending on various social projects (such as education, health care,
and welfare programs for the poor) – known as Structural Adjustment Programs --
in order to, at least, pay the interest on the loan. In addition, those
countries would be maneuvered into selling off their natural resources and
privatizing many aspects of community infrastructure (such as utilities, water,
and transportation) in exchange for certain concessions with respect to their
outstanding debt. Finally, those countries were forced to ‘free’ their banking
system and currencies in a way that rendered their banks and currencies
vulnerable to a systematic dismantling by foreign financiers and banking
interests.
In short, Mr. Perkins job
was to economically destroy countries for the benefit and profit of western
corporations and governments. Everything began with the reports and models he
generated that were intended to induce various western banks and so-called
‘leaders’ in different countries to believe that rosy economic times were just
around the corner if certain sorts of infrastructure projects were initiated,
but what was left unsaid, or hidden, in those reports and models was the fact
that the only people for whom rosy economic times were really being forecast
were western corporations ...
including banks.
The ‘leaders’ of those targeted
countries were manipulated in various ways – through money, sex, power, and
threats – to take out massive loans on ‘behalf’ of the people who, then, would
become responsible for paying back what had been borrowed on their ‘behalf.’ In
other words, small segments from the ‘elite’ of a given country would be bought
off in one way or another, while the generality of people would become the ones
who -- through taxes, inflation, confiscated property, and slashed social
services – had to bear the burden of subsidizing the life styles of western
corporations and corrupt, or corrupted, ‘leaders.’
One of John Perkins
predecessors in the foregoing sort of international intrigue and corporate
manipulation was Kermit Roosevelt, grandson of Theodore Roosevelt. In 1951
Roosevelt – who, at the time, worked for the CIA -- helped to overthrow the
democratically elected Iranian government of Mohammad Mossadegh and replace the
latter individual with Mohammad Reza Pahlavi, the former Shah (or King) of
Iran.
Roosevelt manipulated a
variety of people in Iran -- through money, threats, and the allure of
acquiring power – into staging violent riots and demonstrations in order to
give the false impression that Mossadegh was unpopular with the Iranian people,
as well as that he was a dysfunctional leader. Mossadegh was actually very
popular with the vast majority of Iranians because he had nationalized the oil
industry after his election to office, and this is the reason why the CIA
decided to engage in regime change.
The same tactics have
been used again and again in various parts of the world (e.g., Indonesia,
Guatemala, Cuba, Vietnam, Nicaragua, Haiti, Chile, and Panama ... to name but a
few). The work in which John Perkins became engaged for a time via MAIN was
merely a more politically cosmeticized variation on the original template that
had been introduced by Kermit Roosevelt in 1951.
In other words, rather
than have the CIA directly take charge of projects that altered the economic
and political environment of a country, ‘economists’ like John Perkins would be
sent in to bring about the same sort of results through, seemingly, more
innocuous means. After all, what could be wrong with helping countries to
improve their infrastructure and, thereby, assist those nations to take their
‘rightful’ place at the world economic table? Unfortunately, as pointed
earlier, the entire scenario was a scam intended to, on the one hand, benefit
western corporations and banks, and on the other hand, plunder the resources of
various countries at fire-sale prices while enslaving the populations of those
countries for generations to come.
The World Bank and
International Monetary Fund had become the staging grounds for planning one
economic coup after another. People like John Perkins were the Special Forces’
officers who economically infiltrated countries and helped destroy those
nations from within.
The CIA did not disappear
from the foregoing sort of economic warfare. Their role merely changed in
certain ways.
For example, if ‘leaders’
in a given country would not play along with the economic version of ‘Three
Card Monte’ which had been devised by the World Bank (located in America and largely funded by the United
States), those ‘leaders’ would be offered various incentives to get their head
in the ‘game.’ Some of those incentives were pleasurable and beneficial, while
others ended in death.
In the latter case,
certain elements in the CIA became enforcers for the policies of the ‘economic
mob.’ Mr. Perkins referred to them as ‘jackals.’
In passing, one might
note that John Perkins speaks at some length in several of his books about how
a ‘friend’ of his – Omar Torrijos – encountered a private, real-world version
of the ‘Day of the Jackals.’ At the time, Torrijos was head of state in Panama and, among other things, he had
been instrumental in getting the School of the Americas (a U.S. run school that
had been located in Panama and which taught leaders and military officers from
Central and South America how to oppress, terrorize, and control their own
peoples) thrown out of Panama. Torrijos’ reward for opposing the interests of
the United States in the region was to be eliminated by one, or more, jackals.
The foregoing gives
expression to the real meaning of terms such as: “free markets,” competition,
the invisible hand of the market, and efficiency. In other words the ‘economic
mob’ for which John Perkins once worked busies itself with: rendering markets
free for capital to exploit; eliminating all forms of competition (part of the
process of making markets “free” for capital); being the invisible force that
moves markets in directions that serve the interests of the economic mob, and
efficiently generating profits for corporations and banks at the expense of
local populations who are the ones who actually subsidize those companies.
After nearly fifty years,
my memory is a little hazy on the matter. However, I don’t remember any of my
undergraduate, economic professors discussing the foregoing kinds of activities
when attempting to initiate me into the finer points of microeconomics or
macroeconomics ... maybe something was lost in translation, or, perhaps, I just
wasn’t paying sufficient attention to class discussions or the text materials.
The ‘economic mob’ –
consisting of an amalgamation of corporations, banks, and the United States
government – are ideological psychopaths. They don’t care who they hurt as long
as they get what they want.
In best psychopathic
fashion, the members of the aforementioned mob will use the flowery language
of: freedom, development, democracy, progress, self-regulating markets,
efficiency, leadership, and competition to give expression to the economic
‘miracle’ that is being created in country A, B, or C. Unfortunately, that
language is only being used to camouflage the horror and tragedy of what is
actually transpiring as the people of country after country are cruelly abused,
exploited, manipulated, enslaved, and destroyed by a variety of ‘market
forces.’
While the foregoing
activities are couched in the language of the rule of law, the only rule that
is being manifested is the ‘way of power.’ The people of America have been
induced by representatives of the way of power – whether corporate or
governmental -- to cede moral and intellectual agency to the progenitors of
ideological psychopathy.
There is no way in which
the activities of the ‘economic mob’ can be justified in a manner that, beyond
a reasonable doubt, can be shown to be legitimate expressions of
non-pathological forms of behavior. Unfortunately, all too many representatives
of the executive, congressional, judicial, and state branches of government
have sought to ‘educate’ Americans and, in the process, induce Americans to
accept a delusional and Orwellian-like understanding concerning the nature of
that behavior such that: ‘freedom’ becomes a synonym for oppression, and
‘manipulation’ is relabeled ‘the invisible hand of market forces’, and
‘efficiency’ is a euphemism for the destruction of the environment, people, and
their sovereignty.
-----
Here are some facts to
consider. These facts are among the products of free market capitalistic
economics.
The combined total of the
financial/material wealth of 90 % of households in the United States is less
than the wealth of the top 1 % of households. Furthermore, since the mid-1970s,
all increases in household income have gone to the top 20 % of households.
If one probes the
foregoing data a little more deeply, one learns that during the last 25 years,
or so, there has been a tremendous shift in income levels. More specifically,
in the early part of this century, the top one-tenth of one percent of
taxpayers was collectively earning more income than were the bottom one-third
income levels. Yet, approximately thirty years ago, that same bottom one-third
was collectively earning twice as much income as was the top one-tenth of one
percent of taxpayers.
Over the last fifty
years, the productivity of workers in the United States increased by a little
over 110 %. Nevertheless, during this same period of time, the average hourly
wage went down by about 5 %, and, therefore, in part, increased productivity
was subsidized by lower wages.
Thirty years ago, the
CEOs of a variety of major corporations earned incomes that were about 45 times
the size of non-executive, full-time workers. The foregoing wage rate
differential rose to a factor of 140 times in the early 1990s, and, then a
little over ten years later, the wages of CEOs were approximately 350 times
greater than were the wages earned by most full-time employees in non-executive
positions ... and over the last few years, the wages of CEOs has climbed to
more than 430 times that of regular full-time workers.
During the 1980s, the
average net worth of individuals who were on the Forbes 400 list was around $400
million dollars. In the first decade of the twenty-first century, the average
net worth of those appearing on the Forbes 400 has climbed to nearly 3 billion
dollars.
The average level of
education achieved by workers over the last forty years has risen dramatically
-- with more workers having acquired a high school education than ever before,
and, as well, there has been a doubling of the number of working individuals
who have at least four years of college/university under their belts. Yet, when
adjustments for inflation are factored in, the hourly wage rate for workers has
dropped by more than 10 per cent over the same period of time.
On average, women earn $
.24/hour less than men for doing the same work. Over a forty-year work life,
this pay differential translates into approximately $450,000 for high school
graduates, and the pay differential between men and women doubles to about $
900,000 in relation to individuals who have a bachelor’s degree of some kind.
Moreover, women with a professional degree are likely to earn about two million
dollars less than their male counterparts during the course of their respective
careers.
The differences are even
starker when one factors in race. Nearly half way through the opening decade of
the current century, the median household income for people of color was just
under $25,000/year, while the median household income for whites was nearly
six times higher ... and if one considers the plight of Indians (Native peoples) in particular,
the discrepancies in average earnings are, on average, even worse.
Nearly 50 million people
in the United States subsist at, or below, the poverty level. This includes
millions of children.
Since the financial
debacle of 2007-2008, millions of people have lost their homes and jobs.
Homelessness and hunger are on the increase in the United States.
Companies that have
higher percentages of women in their management groups tend to perform
financially better than those companies that have lower percentages of women on
their management teams. Nonetheless, 95% of the top salary earners at the
largest 500 corporations in the United States are men.
More and more,
corporations are shedding full-time employees and replacing them with part-time
workers. Many of these: contract, leased, and temporary workers are required to
take cuts in pay, benefits, and health care.
In addition, many
corporations are increasingly shifting their operations to other countries
where: labor is cheaper; benefits are non-existent; health and safety standards
are lax or not enforced at all; taxes are low, and there are few, if any,
environmental regulatory laws. Americans either lose their jobs and are told
that the business environment in America must become more competitive – which
is code for the idea that the United States must become just like any number of
third-world countries when it comes to wages, benefits, taxes, regulatory
restraints, and so on.
What if the tables were
turned? What if corporations were told that they have to be far more
competitive with respect to issues of: wages, benefits, safety conditions,
environmental issues, and paying their fair share of taxes or else their
products will not be permitted to be sold in the United States?
Those companies would
likely be screaming about unfair restraint of trade. However, what about unfair
restraint of sovereignty with respect to the vast majority of people in America?
... a form of restraint that is the direct result of corporate activity.
The advocates of free
market capitalism would have us believe that all of the foregoing statistics
reflect: the superiority of whites over other races, or the superiority of men
relative to women, or the superiority of CEOs compared to average workers, or
the superiority of the rich over the poor, or the superiority of free market
enterprise compared to other economic system. However, notwithstanding that
kind of braggadocio and self-promotion, the foregoing differences actually
reflect a system that is rigged to favor: Men over women, whites over people of
color, executives over non-executives, and the rich over the poor.
The foregoing differences
are not a testament to the wealth-producing capacity of free market capitalism.
Those differences are a testament to the way in which free market capitalism
exploits women, workers, people of color, and the poor to subsidize the
life-style of – for the most part -- rich, white, males.
Certain rich, white males
are becoming increasingly wealthy because increasing numbers of women, workers,
and people of color are becoming increasingly poorer. Money is increasingly being siphoned
from the less well-off and channeled into the lives of the more well-off.
Governments – both at the
federal and state levels – as well as many courts and the media are
increasingly serving the interests of corporations. Those corporations need
government, the courts, and the media to arrange things in a favorable manner
for the corporations because otherwise everyone would soon learn that free
market capitalism does not work ... in other words, to whatever extent
so-called free market capitalism succeeds, this is because of the assistance it
receives from productive workers, government subsidies, and coddling from the
judicial system.
Under the right set of
circumstances – ones rooted in the idea of sovereignty -- commercial enterprise
can work to the benefit of everyone. However, commercial enterprise is not
capitalism.
Free market capitalism is
a theoretical fiction with no proven track record. In fact, as the foregoing statistics
point out, the terminal equilibrium point of free market capitalism always
tends toward dividing society into those, on the one hand, who have and, on the
other hand, those who have far less or nothing at all.
Corporations don’t want
the government and the courts to regulate corporate behavior and interfere with
their capacity to generate profits at the expense of the generality of the
people and the environment. From their perspective, that kind of regulation
constitutes interference with the process of free market capitalism.
In best hypocritical
fashion, however, corporations do want government and the courts to regulate:
subsidies, tax codes, mergers, investments, safety conditions, environmental
pollution, and minimum wages in a manner that favors corporate interests. Of
course, the latter sorts of regulatory activities are not considered to be
interference by corporations but, rather, are merely fulfilling the “necessary
and proper” function of the commerce clause.
When free market
capitalism controls issues of sovereignty, one gets the foregoing sorts of
statistics ... and many others that are just as discriminatory, offensive, and
oppressive. The Preamble to the Philadelphia Constitution alludes to the
promise of sovereignty shaping economics (instead of economics controlling
sovereignty), and when understood in this fashion, the ‘commerce clause’
becomes a matter of regulating economic activity in a way that establishes,
protects, and enhances the sovereignty of ‘We the People’ as measured by
qualitative indices such as: justice, tranquility, the common defense, general
welfare, and liberty rather than through the sort of quantitative indices which
show how the rich are growing richer and everyone else is sliding into an
economic abyss.
-----
One of the sacred
principles of free market capitalism is the idea of ‘property.’ However, the
issue of ‘property’ has a very problematic history.
If we restrict ourselves
to just the United States, the nature of the problem becomes quite apparent
fairly quickly. For instance, long before the Pilgrims allegedly landed at
Plymouth Rock, the East India Company was busy claiming land in America on
behalf of English royalty -- just as land in various other parts of the ‘New
World’ was being claimed on behalf of France, Spain, and Holland.
The land being claimed
didn’t belong to the ones doing the claiming. Nevertheless, they proceeded to
claim it anyway.
There was no argument
which the English, French, Spanish, or Dutch could put forth that was capable
of demonstrating, beyond a reasonable doubt, that their property claims were
justified. They did what they did because no one stopped them from doing so.
Possession might
constitute nine-tens of the law in England, France, Spain, and Holland, but the
existence of that sort of a legal idea doesn’t necessarily translate into a
defensible right – one that can be established beyond all reasonable doubt. Of
course, through the use of power and violence, those countries sought to
enforce their arbitrary claims, however, might doesn’t necessarily make a given
action ‘right’ ... although might does often constitute an effective form of
control with respect to those claims.
The East India Company
didn’t have any right to claim land for England that could be proven in a
non-arbitrary manner -- that is, in a way that was evidentially independent of
the mere act of making such a claim. Moreover, the East India Company didn’t have
a non-arbitrarily determined right to cede property/land to the Jamestown
Company.
Similarly, the French
didn’t have a non-arbitrarily determined right to sell its non-arbitrarily
determined possession of ‘Louisiana’ lands, and the United States didn’t have a
non-arbitrarily determined right to make such a purchase. Moreover, the United
States didn’t have a non-arbitrarily determined right to take vast tracts of
land (encompassing the current states of: Nevada, Colorado, California, Utah,
New Mexico, most of Arizona, as well as portions of the present states of:
Oklahoma, Wyoming, Kansas, and Texas) from the Mexicans for nearly 19 million
dollars at the conclusion of a trumped-up war. Nor did the Russians have a non-arbitrarily determined right
to sell Alaska to the United States, any more than Secretary of State William
Seward had a non-arbitrarily determined right to buy his ‘folly.’
Abraham Lincoln didn’t
have a non-arbitrarily determined right to cede land to the railroads.
Moreover, Lincoln didn’t have a non-arbitrarily determined right to cede land
to people via the Homestead Act of 1862.
Many Jewish people
referred to the formation of Israel as being a matter of bringing together, on
the one hand, a people without a land (i.e., the Jewish people), and, on the
other hand, a land without a people (i.e., Palestine). However, as I.F. Stone
observed not too long before his death --
and he was someone who initially supported the idea of Israel but later
came to have concerns about the morality of what had transpired -- Palestine
was never a land without a people.
In like fashion, the
lands being claimed by the East India Company and called Virginia, or the
828,000 acres sold by the French to Jefferson, or the millions of acres
finagled away from the Mexicans by the United States, or the lands purchased by
Seward, on behalf of America, from the Russians, were not empty of people ...
people who had lived on those lands long before the Europeans arrived. Of
course, the fact various Indian nations occupied different parts of the land
that came to be known as the ‘New World, doesn’t necessarily mean that the
lands in questions belonged to the Indian peoples either.
To whom, if anyone, do
the lands, waters, and resources of the world belong? No one has been able to
answer this question in a non-arbitrarily determined fashion.
Everyone has pointed to
sales, treaties, histories, contracts, deeds, eminent domain, and so on in an
attempt to justify their claims to this or that portion of the Earth. All of
those claims have a suspect pedigree.
Like the principle of the
‘chain of custody’ concerning evidence which requires the integrity of that
chain to be preserved and capable of being demonstrated at every point of
transition along the path from crime to courtroom, so too, one must be able to
establish the integrity of ownership when it comes to matters of land and
resources. However, the legitimacy of all claims concerning land and resources
are obscured by everyone’s inability to establish that the evidential and moral
basis on which any initial or original claims concerning land and resources can
be demonstrated, beyond a reasonable doubt, to an array of people who have no
vested interests in such claims.
The law of ignorance
indicates that we don’t know -- in any fashion that can be demonstrated beyond
a reasonable doubt – to whom, if any one, the lands, waters, or resources of
the Earth belong. In essence, the idea that the world belongs to no one seems
less arbitrary than does the idea that the world belongs to particular
individuals, nations, or corporations since the latter claims are all a
function of arguments of dubious validity, whereas the former contention –
i.e., that the world belongs to no one – is consistent with what we can prove
concerning the ultimate nature of Being or is consistent with what can be
demonstrated, beyond a reasonable doubt, with respect to the relationship of
human beings and Being ... which
is nothing at all.
Free market capitalism
wishes to make everything a function of markets, prices, costs, efficiency,
capital, equilibrium conditions, productivity, wealth, competition, profit
margins, rational utility functions, and the like. However, free market
capitalism has never demonstrated beyond a reasonable doubt that its way of
parsing reality is correct – especially when it comes to the issue of
determining who, if anyone, has a non-arbitrarily determined right to reduce
the world and its resources down to parcels of property or packages of
resources which benefit the few, while enslaving and impoverishing the many, as
well as destroying the Earth itself.